MCG top-pageEnglish homepageE-mail

THEORY INDEX

JCP "Theories" of Socialism
(From the Denial of Historical Materialism to Agnosticism)

Written by Kennichi Suzuki (1997)
Translated by Roy West


Contents

Introduction

In the January to March issues of [the JCP's monthly journal] Keizai (Economy), Kikunami Hiroshi discusses the theme: "Thinking About Socialism" in an interview. The apparent purpose of these articles is to explain how the JCP should look back or summarize its former view of the Soviet Union and "theory of socialism", and how to evaluate the former Soviet Union from their "present-day arrival point". These articles are of particular interest because Mr. Kikunami, who now appears to be the chairman of the JCP policy committee, was for many years a fervent proponent and interpreter of the JCP's former theory of a "formative-period of socialism".

In this article we will also look at the views of JCP chairman Fuwa Tetsuzo (expressed in his essay "The Present-Day Development of Our Programmatic Line-On the Revisions From the 20th Party Congress"; presented over five issues of the JCP's theoretical journal Zen'ei (Vanguard) starting in January 1995), which is likely the basis for Kikunami's own views. Of course, in order to verify his "consistency", we will also refer to some of Kikunami's earlier writings. The quotations from the three recent interviews with Kikunami are referred to as #1, #2, and #3.

"Present-day" Arrival Point of the JCP's Theory of Socialism-The Presupposition that the USSR was a Socialist System

Before considering Kikunami's statements, for the sake of younger readers I would like to briefly look back at the JCP's theory of the Soviet Union (socialism). This should help clarify the "difference" between their past and "present-day" point of arrival.

For the reconstructed postwar JCP, led by Tokuda Ky?ichi and Shiga Yoshio on the fundamental basis of the 1932 Comintern Thesis on Japan(*1), it was assumed that the Soviet Union was socialist. The Soviet Communist Party and Stalin were the object of reverence and worship. In the [JCP daily newspaper] Akahata (Red Banner) at the time, Stalin's birthday was greeted ever year with enormous headlines praising Stalin as "our great leader". This was almost identical to the worship of Kim Il Sung and Kim Chong-Il in North Korea.

(*1)There were several Comintern Thesis on Japan in the prewar period that strongly influenced the JCP's program. The 1932 Thesis stressed that the "path to the dictatorship of the proletariat can only be through a bourgeois-democratic revolution", and that this revolution would have a "tendency to grow rapidly into a socialist revolution".

The postwar JCP inherited, almost unchanged, the 1932 Comintern thesis which defined the Japanese revolution as a "democratic revolution", and spread the fantasy about a "peaceful revolution under the occupation". Consequently, they not only squandered the best opportunity for postwar revolution, but also channeled the rising class struggles of the workers into a dead-end. With the intensification of the Cold War, the collapse of the daydream of "peaceful revolution", and the Cominform's criticism of the JCP, the party suddenly split in 1950, and the Tokuda "Mainstream faction", supported by Stalin, grabbed the leadership amidst a gruesome, unremitting factional fight with Miyamoto Kenji's "International faction". When Secretary-General Miyamoto (at the time) was finally able to gain control of the reins of power with the death of Stalin and Tokuda and Khrushchev's criticism of Stalin, the Hungarian uprising broke out. The JCP's reaction to this uprising vividly revealed the Stalinist nature of this party.

The Hungarian uprising from October to November 1956, like the Poznan riots in Poland several months earlier, was a rebellion against the exploitation and repression of the workers by the Stalinist Communist Party bureaucracy. When this uprising was crushed by the Soviet tanks, it was a serious blow and setback for Communist Parties throughout the world. In Japan, and many other economically developed countries, this marked, at least among advanced workers and students, the beginning of opposition to the JCP, or a distancing from the party, and was the starting point for the building of a new workers party.

But the consistent attitude of the JCP at the time was to call the Hungarian uprising "counter-revolutionary", and express overall support for the Soviet repression. After initially maintaining a baffled silence, some evasive editorials were written in Akahata, but with the success of Soviet suppression, the pages were filled with headlines such as "Oppose Imperialist Intervention In Hungary", or "Crush The Counter-Revolution In Hungary".

Secretary-General Miyamoto, who was establishing his position as the top leader of the JCP, also denounced the Hungarian uprising as counter-revolutionary, while arguing for the firm unity of the party. According to Miyamoto, one of the reasons that the uprising occurred was that "the Hungarian Communist Party was not internally united, and the Party's internal arguments were taken outside and utilized by counter-revolutionary forces". As a result, "problems which should naturally be solved by socialistic, democratic methods led to violent struggles for counter revolutionary purposes." Miyamoto concluded that, "a system must be maintained whereby we can strengthen unity and uphold the party laws, while correcting flaws through the power of unity."(*2) This is the main lesson that he drew from the Hungarian incident. What a fitting "summation" for a Stalinist party bureaucrat.

(*2)Miyamoto Kenji, "Hangarii mondai wo ikani hy?ka suru ka [How to Evaluate the Hungarian Problem] (Zen'ei, February 1957).

The subsequent change in the JCP's view of the Hungarian uprising can be seen in their Sixty-Year History of Japanese Communist Party, published in July 1982 to commemorate the sixtieth anniversary of the party's foundation. Here the uprisings in Poland and Hungary are placed side by side in the following context:

In some socialist countries in Eastern Europe, working people rose in a struggle against the pressure of Soviet great-power hegemonism over the years, and against bureacraticism associated with it, resulting in a critical situation.(*3)

(*3)Central Committee Japanese Communist Party, Sixty-Year History of the Japanese Communist Party 1922-1982 (Tokyo: Japan Press Service, 1984), p. 194The Hungarian uprising is then described in the following way:

Concerning the "Hungarian incident", there are a large number of materials and testimonies available, published over more than twenty years. Not only was the JCP subject to historical restrictions because the incident occurred before the Seventh JCP Congress was held, but it also had no direct means of obtaining correct information. The statements made by the JCP at that time therefore, under these circumstances must be the subject of re-examination, based on our achievements in the independent study of international politics so far.(*4)

(*4)Ibid., p. 195.Even at the beginning of the eighties, more than "twenty years" after the Hungarian uprising, the JCP merely suggests that "materials" and "testimonies" should be "the subject of re-examination", and are unable to clearly give an overview of their former standpoint. What a pathetic "vanguard".

In the Sixty-five Year History of the Japanese Communist Party, published in March 1988, perhaps because they finally got hold of these elusive "materials and testimonies", their description is more detailed and their evaluation is different. According to this new account:

The demands and the movement of the Hungarian people stemmed from a desire for national freedom from Soviet hegemonism and a multi-party political system. Even though this included some maneuvers by reactionary elements, on the whole it could not be called a counter-revolutionary scheme from abroad. In the Hungarian incident, the Soviet military action was an interventionist act which ran counter to the principles of socialism and the rights of self-determination.(*5)

(*5)Translated from Japanese edition of Sixty-Five Year History of the Japanese Communist Party, pp. 154-5.This is a liberalist account of the "demands and movement of the Hungarian people" that reveals the fundamental limitations of the JCP. Notwithstanding this, however, they are essentially denying their former view that the struggles of the Hungarian people were "counter-revolutionary actions". From this, the question naturally arises of how to view the actions of then Secretary-General Miyamoto, and other JCP leaders should be evaluated However, no such consideration or self-criticism is present in the Sixty-Five Year History of the Japanese Communist Party. This is the sort of self-transformation on the installment plan that the JCP favors. Irresponsible and opportunism truly run to the marrow of this party.

The theory of the "Formative-Period of Socialism"

The Communist Party set out its theory of the "formative-period of socialism" at its 14th Party Congress:

The world-historic transition from capitalism to socialism is to be effected as a process by which countries that have already taken the road of socialism advance to full-fledged development, overcoming their historic constraints; the process by which the peoples of various capitalist countries start on the road of socialist transition to attain full socialist development, suited to their own countries, via the route of democratic transition and so on, and the process by which the nations of Asia, Africa, and Latin America break free of the domination of new and old colonialism and take the road to national self-determination and social progress under the conditions that are peculiar to each, with their own respective forms. It is necessary for us to grasp the following point from the principled viewpoint of scientific socialism: All these processes combine to form a mighty current. Only by combining these processes can socialism free itself of initial formation, and reach a new stage in which socialism can give full play to its inherit superiority and vitality.(*6)

(*6)"Resolution of the 14th Congress of the JCP", quoted from Sixty Year History, p. 517.It should be noted here that at the basis of this "definition" of the "formation-period socialism" theory is the assumption that the USSR, China and Eastern European countries are "socialist states". Since various "negative phenomena" could not be denied outright, they attempt to "explain" this with the idea that they stem from the "formative-stage", i.e. the development stage. This can be easily understood from Chairman Miyamoto's address to the congress:

In the long history of mankind, only one and a half centuries have passed since the birth of the communist concept, and it is only sixty years since the first socialist country was established, and in this sense the progress made by mankind over this period is very great. But, taking a broad view of history, we see that the socialist world is still in its infancy, with a great number of countries still capitalist. It would be childish to feel despair over the fact that the ideals of communism, cherished by the originators of theories of scientific socialism or communism, have not yet bloomed fully.(*7)

(*7)Ibid., p. 517.This inane theory was then defended for twenty years as the official view of the JCP, and Fuwa and Kikunami produced a rhetorical flood to defend and explain this theory.

"The USSR wasn't Socialist at all"?

However, at the Twentieth Party Congress, after the collapse of the Soviet Union, Fuwa Tetsuzo stated in his Chairman' Report, that the Soviet Union was "neither a socialist society, nor a society in a transition to socialism". The JCP Central Committee member Adachi Masatsune's "explained" the decision of the Twentieth Congress and its significance as having "a great impact both inside and outside the party". According to Adachi, after studying and discussing the resolutions of the Congress, many responded that "it made them happy to be JCP members", or that "it renewed their pride and confidence as party members":

One of the problems which raised the liveliest discussion and made a strong impression on party members was the Congress elucidation of the theory of socialism. In the amendment to the Party program adopted at the Congress, along with the indication that the former Soviet Union and Eastern European countries were hegemonists and bureaucratic with nothing in common to socialism, was the description that "in these countries, starting with the revolution, the goal of aiming for socialism was held out, but because of the mistaken path followed by the leadership, the society was actually unable to reach socialist society, and met with dissolution." Moreover, in the "report on the amendment of the program", it was clarified that the Soviet Union from the time of Stalin "carried out fundamentally mistaken policies in the realm of economics, and thus the transitional period that Lenin was striving for thrown was thrown off the rails", and that "it is obvious that a society cannot be called socialism, or even a transitional society, if it eliminates people's economic control of agriculture and industry, oppresses them, and is sustained by a prison labor force numbering in the hundreds of thousands". Furthermore, while emphasizing that the JCP's theory of the "formative-period of socialism" elaborated at the Fourteenth Party Congress represented an independent view at a time when the Soviet Union and other countries defined themselves as "developed socialism" and forced this view on other countries, it was still pointed out that "seen from the present-day, this view that the Soviet Union was, by and large, a historical transitional society, despite containing many defects and negative phenomena, lacked clarity". In response to the question, which naturally arose: "what was Soviet Society then?" the attitude was to "avoid dogmatic schemas" and stress the importance of concrete, analytical research.(*8)

(*8)Adachi Masatsune, "Dai nij?kai t?daikai ni miru shakaishugi-ron no hatten" [The Development of the Theory of Socialism at the Twentieth Party Congress] in Zen'ei February 1994.According to Adachi, this analysis "has great historical significance internationally" not only in Japan, and the individual response from congress delegates was that it was "masterful", or that they "received a sort of intellectual shock", and "the common view was a feeling of relief and sympathy". He wants to say how great this was for the JCP members, but no matter how much the JCP is proud of its "monolithic" unity, there is no way that such a 180-degree change cannot cause some friction. Let's listen to some more of his report:

At the same time, naturally, doubts and questions were raised concerning the proposal of the Congress. Most fundamentally accepted the conclusion of the Congress, but said something to the effect that "it was too sudden to say that the USSR wasn't socialist", or "this contradicted the theory of the "formative- period theory". A few people reacted by saying "does this mean that I believed in vain the USSR was socialist" or "why are we saying this now". There was also some tendency, apart from the overall decisions of the Congress, to focus on how to view the former Soviet Union.(*9)

(*9)Ibid.Even Chairman Fuwa recognized the discord within the party, and wrote that, "the conclusion of the Congress (that the 'USSR was neither socialism nor a transitional society), led a few to argue 'why wasn't this said thirty years ago'." But Fuwa quickly added:

However, it is important to note that, internationally speaking, the JCP showed extreme foresight in developing an understanding of the hegemonism of the USSR and other errors.(*10)

(*10)Fuwa Tetsuzo, Zen'ei, January 1995.Fuwa was thus very busy offering up long-winded explanations, and Kikunami's interview can be viewed as one part of the effort by the leadership to achieve some consistency in their views.

Did Hegemonism Cause the Collapse of the USSR?

Kikunami's interview begins with the question of why the Soviet and Eastern European systems collapsed. His response is that hegemonism led to the collapse of the Soviet Union:

To start with my conclusion, for the USSR to hold out, under the international conditions I just mentioned, the Soviet leadership after Stalin resisted the imperialist hegemonism with their own hegemonism, and turned into a hegemonic state, this in turn led to mission to imperialism and self-collapse.(*11)

(*11)Kikunami, #1, p. 72.This is another fine example the JCP's "scientific socialism"(*12). The collapse of the USSR is said to have been caused by the "mistaken" ideology of hegemonism, and foreign policy. No trace of historical materialism can be found in Kikunami's argument, which explains the collapse and deadlock of the Soviet state starting from ideology and policies. The ideology and foreign policy of a state can only be rationally explained-naturally presupposing certain historical and international conditions-from the class character and internal class relations of the state in question, not the reverse. The fact that the Soviet Union pursued a hegemonic course means that it was a bourgeois state, not that it merely "deviated from the principles of socialism".

(*12)The JCP still professes, despite all of the evidence to the contrary, that they are upholding "scientific socialism".

Furthermore, before discussing the "deviation from the principles of socialism", it is necessary to demonstrate that the country in question was in fact a socialist state. When discussing the reasons for the collapse of the Soviet Union, the JCP unconsciously presupposes that the Soviet Union was socialist, but in fact this contradicts the declaration of their own Twentieth Congress? Of course, being totally oblivious to his own opportunism, Kikunami could never realize this. There may be some who would find nothing wrong with Kikunami's foolish attempt to explain the Soviet Union's collapse starting from some ideology or another, so let's follow Kikunami's line of reasoning a bit further.

Kikunami' criticizes Gorbachev's "New Thinking" which advocated the peaceful co-existence of the two systems in order to end "class conflict and the confrontation of social systems" and bring about the formation of a "new civilized" society. For Kikunami, this represented a "political and ideological" submission to imperialism", which "led to the avalanche-like self-collapse of the Soviet Union":

The core of the problem is that, from the time of Stalin, the Soviet leadership ignored the power of the people, turned into a great-power hegemonic state, and finally submitted to imperialism, this indeed led to "self-collapse". The collapse of the Soviet Union was the failure of Soviet hegemonism.(*13)

(*13)Ibid., p. 76.

The leadership itself self-collapsed ideologically, and their power was crushed. On this point, the human causes of the Soviet collapse are extremely important."(*14)

(*14)Ibid., p. 80.As we can see, Kikunami declares that the USSR collapsed because its leadership fell into hegemonism and "ideologically self-destructed". Someone who explains the collapse of the USSR from an "ideological breakdown", will naturally seek the cause of this collapse in "human factors". This is historical idealism, needless to say, and opens the path to arbitrary explanations of history, such as the idea that the Soviet Union would not have collapsed had its leaders been more ideologically sound or intellectually firm.

There may be some who think that Kikunami is trying to say that hegemonism sped up the Soviet Union's military expansionism, and hastened its collapse by worsening its contradictions. Certainly, Kikunami does say something to this effect (especially in the second interview). But this still does not dissolve the problem. Hegemonism is not simply a problem of the Soviet Union, but is rather a line "applied" or inevitable path taken by more or less all bourgeois states, particularly large bourgeois states. Today the United States is openly declaring its supremacy, and recently China is advancing an open hegemonism. It is also well known that Japan is burning with a desire to establish hegemony in Asia. But these countries are not necessarily on the verge of collapse, and this reveals the falseness of the idea that hegemonism could be the direct cause of a state's collapse.

Of course, hegemonism can certainly deepen the contradictions of a system, but if it is linked to the collapse of a system this is due to the internal factors are the cause of collapse. In other words, within a system there are elements which make hegemonism necessary, these deepen the system's contradictions, and prepare (speed) its collapse, but it is historical idealism to separate hegemonism from the socio- economic foundation of the system, and view it as the cause of a system's collapse. Kikunami's discussion is nothing but idealistic, moralistic prattle. The issue is what makes hegemonism necessary, how do the internal contradictions of a country lead to the collapse of the system. Kikunami has not even one word to say on this essential point.

Evaluation of the Russian Revolution and NEP

In the second interview, Kikunami talks about the "domestic factors in the collapse of the USSR and Eastern Europe", but this only exposes the arbitrariness of the JCP's theory. Kikunami "spent four years (1960-64) living in the Soviet Union", during which time he found it a monotonous society, and felt some doubts about a country that only reported goals of production that were achieved. (He triumphantly says in the interview that when he visited East Germany in 1972, he had the "intuition" that "if this country relaxed it would probably collapse". A very easy thing to say in hindsight!) His recollections reveal that while he had serious misgivings, he clung to "common sense" instead of thoroughly investigating the matter.

Kikunami offers a pathetic "historical overview" by dividing the history of the Soviet Union into four periods. According to his account, the Russian Revolution was a "socialist revolution", the period of NEP was "a very active society" in which "a government aiming for socialism implemented policies for workers and Russia was full of a new spirit of the people."(*14) However, as we have repeatedly indicated, the class character of the Russian Revolution cannot be defined simply as a "socialist revolution". In a late developing country such as Russia, where the peasantry made up eighty percent of the population, the revolution was not "socialist", in the full meaning of the word, in terms of socio-economic content, and could only be a democratic revolution of the workers and peasants. The fact that the Russia Revolution contained proletarian socialist elements stemming from the fact that the workers assumed hegemony, does not change the socio-economic character of the revolution.

(*15)Kikunami, #2, pp. 108-9.

If one defines the Russian Revolution, without reservation, as a "socialist revolution", why did the development of productive power through NEP (i.e. capitalism), and the establishment of state capitalism become a real task? Furthermore, how can one account for the reversal from "wartime communism" to NEP? Kikunami does not even consider these obvious questions. To use a paradoxical expression, after the October "socialist" revolution in Russia, the large-scale development of capitalism had to begin.

We must point also out that the NEP period cannot be glorified in the manner of Kikunami. Certainly, by means of NEP the Soviet economy, which had collapsed from internal and foreign war, was able at last to begin its revival, but in this process there was also an intensification of contradictions, such as the growing disequilibrium between agriculture and industry, a drop in the price of agricultural goods relative to industrial articles (scissors crisis), the class stratification of the peasantry with the expansion of the power of rich peasants (kulaks), the Nepmen's intrigues and speculative activity, etc. These contradictions of NEP were reflected within the Soviet Communist Party in the form of the bitter debate over the line of industrialization, and the corresponding development of factional struggles. It was the development under NEP of these internal contradictions of Russian society that led to the forced establishment of state capitalism under Stalin.

It is natural that Kikunami, who one-dimensionally glorifies NEP with no awareness of its internal contradictions, is only able to moralistically criticize Stalin for violently ending NEP and collectivizing agriculture thereby suddenly changing Soviet society (or to borrow the expression from the interview: "this threw Soviet Society off the track of a transitional period aiming for socialism"). Kikunami "defines" the Stalinist system as "a despotic and bureaucratic system", but leaves it at that. This is his only definition, and he has nothing to say about the historical and class nature of this system! What he calls "scientific socialism" is crude beyond belief.

He goes on to describe Soviet society after Stalin as "having no internal drive to develop productive power", "piling up waste and inefficiency and a widening black-market economy", "turning its back on science and technology", and as "a stagnant society lacking democracy".(*16) What more could he possibly say? But even while providing a detailed list of the "limitations" and "defects" of Soviet society, he seems to be unaware (perhaps intentionally) that he is exposing his own ignorance for formerly championing this country as an example of socialist society.

(*16)Ibid., p. 112.

Kikunami's "Overview" of the "Formative-Stage" Theory
The development of human cognition?

In the third interview, Kikunami finally responds to the question of "what sort of system the USSR was exactly" and explains the "arrival point" of the Twentieth Party Congress which declared: "the Soviet Union was unable to reach socialism, and by creating the Stalinist system through the violent interruption of NEP, this society, from the time of Stalin, strayed from the transitional period aiming for socialism". Kikunami then responds to the "penetrating question" of the relationship between this theory and the former "formative-period theory of socialism". The following passages should be remembered as a testament to Kikunami's (and the JCP's) confusion:

I think this is related to the development of people's understanding since the collapse of the Soviet Union. At least this is the case for me. Previously I thought that there was no reason to think that the Soviet Union was not socialist. Of course, even though I thought the USSR was socialism, I did not think or say that it was a "model" of socialism, or at least not once I had started to seriously think (?!) about socialism.(*17)

(*17)Kikunami, #3, p. 100.It seems that Mr. Kikunami did "not seriously think about socialism" until the Soviet Union collapsed. He had been convinced that the USSR was socialist and had announced this, but now he seems to have finally realized his error. However, since it is rather uncomfortable to directly admit this, he instead talks about the "development of people's understanding" since the collapse of the Soviet Union.

Kikunami displays a pride in a "displaying a sort of decisiveness and ability to discriminate". He admits his error, but without any trace of self-criticism or serious reflection. In fact, when Kikunami says, "in the past I said this and advanced the theory of a 'formative-period', so I unequivocally, and clearly decided that there was a need for adjustments [in the theory]"(*18) Since today there can no longer be "adjustments" made, his "decisiveness" can only mean throwing this theory away. Kikunami continues:

(*18)Ibid., p. 101.

From the seventies, this question (how to evaluate the Soviet Union) was seriously discussed, theoretically and academically", before that time the question of whether the USSR was socialism did not even enter into discussion, it was a matter of common sense.(*19)

(*19)Ibid.What nonsense! The question of how to evaluate the USSR dates all the way back to the time of Trotsky, and was discussed in the postwar period in the fifties and sixties by Tsushima Tadayuki, Tony Cliff and others, but the JCP simply ignored these debates. Kikunami's "criticism" of Trotsky or Tsushima boils down to the fact that he never "seriously" engaged with their arguments. It is upsetting to hear him go so far as to say that it was "common knowledge" that the Soviet Union was socialism. For Kikunami, if something is not discussed within the Communist Party, it simply does not exist. This brings to mind the expression "the frog in the well knows nothing of the great ocean". Kikunami argues that since objectively it was "common knowledge" that the Soviet Union was socialist, the JCP also followed this "common knowledge". The problem thus lies with "common sense", not the Communist Party. What a lovely theory. But already "common knowledge" is not the truth or science. Science begins with the questioning of common sense. Or is Kikunami saying that the job for theorists of "scientific socialism" is to simply follow "common sense"? If this were so there would be absolutely no need for such theorists in the first place.

The Role of the "Formative-Period" Theory

Kikunami goes on to defend the theory of the "formative-period of socialism" saying that it "was the foundation for a coolheaded criticism of the Soviet Union", but despite the amendment of the term "formative-period", he still committed a fundamental mistake in evaluating the Soviet Union as "socialism". Here we will look at recent JCP statements concerning the theory of a "formative-period of socialism". Fuwa, for example, offers the self-flattering idea that "our party's theory of a 'formative-period' of socialism had resounding significance within the world communist movement which was dominated from the time of Stalin by the theory of the "completion of socialism". He then speaks of the "significance" and "limitations" of the JCP's theory:

This theory of the "formative" period played an extremely important role internationally, and was the independent insight of the JCP. However, from the perspective of the position reached today, it has major theoretical limitations. This is because it adopted the view that the Soviet Union, although full of negative phenomena resulting from many mistakes and deviations, was ultimately a society belonging to a "transitional period" to socialism.(*20)

(*20)Fuwa, p. 36.Cunning Mr. Fuwa has replaced the "formative-period of socialism" with "a society belonging to a 'transitional period' to socialism". But regardless of whether the embarrassing term to be carefully avoided is "transitional period" or "formative-period", he still basically evaluated the Soviet Union as "socialism", and the question of the objective meaning of this word remains.

Here must also reluctantly take a look at the past statements of Mr. Kikunami. Beginning in the eighties, Kikunami argued against the "socialist economist" Nagasuna Minoru, and defended the theory of a "formative-period".(*21) This debate itself doesn't amount to much, and the views of Kikunami can be evaluated at a glance. Nagasuna (relying on Marx's Critique of the Gotha Programme) argued that the "formative-period theory" amounted to nothing more than an understanding of the current situation which can explain the develop- mental stage of various countries as a "traditional developmental stage theory", but cannot explain the particular developmental stage of socialism in each country, and it is correct to define the contemporary Soviet Union as a "maturing and developing socialism" with remnants of backwardness (in other words he defended the standpoint of the Soviet Communist Party).

(*21)Kikunami, "Nihon ky?sant? no shakaishugi "seiseiki" ron hihansha e no kait?" [A Response to a Critic of the JCP's Theory of a "Formative-Period" of Socialism], in Zen'ei, March 1982.

Kikunami countered with the argument that the "standpoint which defines the developmental stage of each country by focusing on the degree of the socialization of the means of production" was insufficient, and that the developmental stage of productive power must also be considered. On this point, he said that the Soviet Union was backward, and could not be called "developed socialism" (to prove this backwardness Kikunami mentioned all sorts of statistics related to the productive power of steel, cement, and electric power).

On the other hand, however, Kikunami emphasized that the Soviet Union was a society with socialized means of production and no exploitation. He stressed that there is great historical significance in the fact that private ownership of the means of production has fundamentally been abolished, and production relations have been established which do not require exploitation:

One certainly cannot overlook the fact that relations of exploitation have been abolished in the Soviet Union by establishing the social ownership of the means of production.(*22)

(*22)Ibid., p. 121.In other words, Kikunami claims that in the USSR the means of production were socialized and exploitation abolished, but because the level of productive power was lower than that of advanced Western capitalist states, it could not be called "developed capitalism", and instead should be called a "formative-period of socialism". He expressed this idea directly in the following passage:

This particular backwardness and difficulties have marked the present-day socialist countries with many complicated limitations and characteristics. This has created a special circumstance wherein even though, in line with the critical examination of Nagasuna, the socialization of the means of production has been "100%" established, productive power still lags behind the level of advanced capitalist countries.(*23)

(*23)Ibid., pp. 115-6.Kikunami, as he states later in the interview, has now changed his view of the socialization of the means of production, but his statement above clearly shows that, at least in terms of his official statements, the theory of a "formative-period of socialism" defended and beautified the Soviet system. If a distinction were to be drawn between the theory of "developed socialism" and the theory of a "formative-period", it would only be that the former openly beautified the Soviet Union, while the latter is a shamefaced or hidden glorification of the Soviet Union.

The theory of a "formative-period of socialism" is not only a beautification of the USSR in this fundamental sense. That is, along with pointing out the difficulties and contradictions of the "formative- period", this theory also often emphasized the system's "affirmative aspects" as socialism. For example, in speaking of the "formative- period of socialism", Miyamoto often mentioned "positive aspects" such as the comprehensive welfare system, free education, and social security. In speaking of East Germany, Kikunami also added:

Of course, there are many things that were better in East Germany than West Germany. Education was free up to the university level, and there was a good system of social security and welfare. When we spoke of the systematic superiority, we were referring to these aspects. [Today after the collapse of East Germany] Everybody does not now have social security or welfare.(*24)

(*24)Kikunami, #1, p. 68.From these sorts of statements, it is clear that the theory of the "formative-period of socialism", on the whole, served the role of glorifying Soviet society.

This theory of the "formative-period of socialism", as we already mentioned, was first introduced at the Fourteenth Party Congress in 1977. Already by this time (to borrow the description of Kikunami), "to serious debates in Japan and throughout the world over the nature of the Soviet Union arose in the wake of such events as the intensification of Sino-Soviet conflict, the extreme violent destructive interference towards the JCP, the Soviet attitude towards the Vietnam War, the invasion of Czechoslovakia and armed repression of the revived socialist movement there, Roy Medvedev's revelation of Stalin's mass oppression (published in Japan from 1973-77), the exposure of the kolhozy and other internal conditions, the stagnation of the Soviet economy and debates over profit". Needless to say, these are important questions (with the exception of the question of "intervention" in JCP affairs) which fundamentally called into question the theory of Soviet socialism. Nevertheless, the JCP was content to simply counter the theory of "developed socialism" with their theory of the "formative-period of socialism". One can see the JCP's theoretical superficiality and insensitivity to reality in their tendency to cling to the Stalinist dogmas, to which they constantly adjusted.

The Denial of State Capitalism and the Agnosticism Tendency
Kikunami's discussion of the socialization of production

We have already touched on Kikunami's view, expressed in his theory of the "formative-stage of socialism", that the means of production were "100%" socialized in the Soviet Union. But recently Kikunami is saying that the nationalization of the means of production does not necessarily signify socialization if the workers are not in control of production. It should be immediately clear from a glance at the reality of monopoly capitalism and state monopoly capitalism today that the nationalization of the means of production does not signify "socialization". At the beginning of the twentieth century, national companies appeared in many capitalist countries, but this did not in any way change the fact that these were capitalist countries. What then is the substance of Kikunami's understanding of the socialization of production? Let's listen to his explanation:

The socialization of the means of production means that they change from the private ownership of capitalists to become the possession of the nation. They once again become the possession of society. However, this is not merely an economic act. I have thought about this for some time. The state which acquires the means of production must be a democratic state of the workers. If this is not the case and the state is anti-democratic, no matter what form of nationalization occurs, the means of production will not become the possession of the citizens, and will not be socialized.(*25)

(*25)Kikunami, #3, p. 105.At a glance this may appear to be a plausible explanation, but in fact it contains an ambiguity that leads to opportunism. As Engels' pointed out, the capitalist mode of production "forces on more and more the transformation of the vast means of production, already socialized, into state property"(*26) , but overall socialization is only possible through the establishment of proletarian political power. And this power, or workers' state, is at the same time a state that is "withering away":

(*26)Engels, Anti-Duhring p. 267

The proletariat seizes political power and turns the means of production in the first instance into state property. But, in doing this, it abolishes itself as proletariat, abolishes all class distinctions and class antagonisms, abolishes also the state as state.(*27)

(*27)Ibid.

The state was the official representative of society as a whole; the gathering of it together into a visible embodiment. But it was only in so far as it was the state of that class which itself represented, for the time being, society as a whole: in ancient times, the state of slave-owning citizens; in the Middle Ages, the feudal lords; in our time, the bourgeoisie. When at last it becomes the real representative of the whole of society, it renders itself unnecessary. As soon as there is no longer any social class to be held in subjection; as soon as class rule, and the individual struggle for existence based upon our present anarchy in production, with the collisions and excesses arising from these, are removed, nothing more remains to be repressed, and a special repressive force, a state, is no longer necessary. The first act by virtue of which the state really constitutes itself the representative of the whole of society-the taking into possession of the means of production in the name of society-that is, at the same time, its last independent act as a state. State interference in social relations becomes, in one domain after another, superfluous, and then dies out of itself; the government of persons is replaced by the administration of things, and by the conduct of processes of production. The state is not 'abolished'. It dies out.(*28)

(*28)Ibid., pp. 267-68.Proletarian power abolishes the private ownership of the means of production in "the first act by virtue of which the state really constitutes itself as the representative of the whole of society-the taking into possession of the means of production in the name of society", and thus turns into a sort of socio-economic organization to shoulder "the administration of things" and the "processes of production".

This essential point is not clear in Kikunami's "explanation". While he talks about the socialization of the means of production and proletarian political power (workers' state), and the fact that this state is already not a state in the original sense, but a "half-state" which is "dying out", he makes absolutely no mention that the private ownership of the means of production is abolished and class divisions overcome. For him the task is not a proletarian revolution to establish the power of a workers' state, but democratic reforms to "democratize" the state and society. His explanation of the socialization of the means of production is a sort of cunning maneuver to replace social revolution with social reform.

From Historical Idealism to Know-Nothingism
Kikunami's "Present-day" point of arrival

At the very end of the interview, Kikunami finally mentions the theory of state capitalism. But nothing he says is clear, and after saying that it is not this or that, or commenting on how it is "a difficult question", he ultimately denies the theory of state capitalism. After very briefly introducing Lenin and Plekhanov's theories of state capitalism, he sums up "the current theory of state capitalism" in the following way:

There are many differences in the basis of theories of state capitalism today, but they are generally characterized by the definition of the "workers being directly engaged in wage labor" or the relationship between the directors of state enterprises and workers being one of wage-workers. So instead of describing the method of production as capitalistic, they define it as being capitalism itself. The basic characteristic of the theory of state capitalism, despite various nuances, is that the means of production were nationalized, but it was capitalism dominated by wage labor.(*29)

(*29)Kikunami, #3, p. 112.In response to the interviewer's query of Kikunami's personal view, he answers:

That's a difficult one. To speak of wage labor assumes the existence of a bourgeois class on the other hand. But there is the question of whether this class really existed in the USSR? For this reason, one cannot easily say whether the term wage-workers should be used or not. Certainly there were wage-worker-like conditions. But the main question is whether or not the workers were the masters of production. I think that the Soviet Union was a society ruled by the bureaucracy-a bureaucratic layer with special privileges. Even if one uses the word class, this does not mean that they were the owners of the means of production.(*30)

(*30)Ibid.What Kikunami is saying boils down to the idea that the workers "worked under wage-worker-like conditions" but he can't be sure if they should be defined as wage-workers, and the bureaucracy ruled the society, but he can't be sure if they should be called a bourgeoisie ("difficult questions"!). We have already fully examined and solved the question of the relationship between capital and wage labor in the USSR and the position of the bureaucracy over thirty years ago when we established our theory of state capitalism. To repeat this here would be a waste of time. One need only refer to Hayashi's long essay on the Soviet System(*31), and subsequent writings.

(*31)See chapter 6.

The interviewer mentioned that there "is a view that state capitalism must be understood in the historical process as a way for backward countries to industrialize", but Kikunami made a quick getaway by mumbling that it would be inappropriate to say that state capitalism was inevitable for industrial construction since this would imply that the Stalinist system was "inevitable". The following passage clearly shows that Kikunami understands nothing about the essence of the problem:

It is a fact that the October Revolution aimed for socialism. So from the viewpoint of historical materialism, it would be strange to say that state capitalism came about through this, and that this then became actual capitalism.(*32)

(*32)Ibid., p. 114.As we pointed out above, in terms of its socio-economic content, the Russian Revolution-due to the late developmental stage of Russian society-was not a "socialist revolution", and there was no choice but to propel forward commodity production and distribution and "guide this along the rails of state capitalism" (Lenin). The subsequent development in Russia shows that state capitalism could not stop at the level of capitalism controlled and regulated by the workers' and peasants' state as Lenin had thought. State capitalism was established as a system that encompassed the entire society through the nationalization of all industry and forced agricultural collectivization. Furthermore, because the Russian system took the form of state capitalism (a particular type of capitalism), liberalization became necessary, and the collapse of the Soviet Union meant that this suppressed bourgeois nature could develop overall. This is in fact the consistent viewpoint of historical materialism. Kikunami denies the theory of state capitalism, but is completely unable to answer the question of how to positively define the Soviet system:

In terms of how to define the economic social structure of the USSR, as I said before, this is difficult [fourth time-Suzuki]. At the Twentieth Party Congress, Chairman Fuwa said that "there were no restrictions on scientific research at this point", and adopted the attitude of leaving the serious study to those who wish to undertake it. I think this is a very wise attitude. However, he added that "phrasing the question in terms of a choice between socialism or capitalism is not a scientific approach", and stressed that it was necessary to take a wider view and avoid being dogmatic or schematic. I think that this is the most important thing to remember when looking at the complex Soviet society.(*33)

(*33)Ibid., pp. 114-5.Here Kikunami sounds quite self-important, but he is basically just admitting that he doesn't know how the Soviet system should be defined. He really is taking his joke too far, however, when he says that Soviet society is a "complex" enigma so one should not fall into the standpoint of saying whether it was capitalism or socialism. Since the October revolution, the Russian "socialist system" lasted for more than seventy years as an "economic social structure". A political party unable to scientifically elucidate this system certainly cannot hold up the banner of "scientific socialism". When faced with this important problem that lies at the heart of the essence of contemporary society, for a political party to simply say that it is a difficult question, amounts to their own self-negation. After confessing that he had "no conclusion to present to this difficult [fifth time!] problem", Kikunami goes on to say:

I don't think that it is possible understand the Soviet Union by squeezing a complex society into one category-for example, state capitalism, semi-feudal society, or slave society, etc. The only thing that can be done is to view it in its totality just as it is. This may seem evasive [it sure is!-Suzuki], but I don't think there is any better way.(*34)

(*34)Ibid., p. 115.I also frankly think that from the perspective of historical materialism it is not necessarily a requirement to define each type of economic social system.

This is the end of the interview. Kikunami sidesteps the question of his own incompetence, and plainly states that from the "perspective of historical materialism" no definition of the USSR is needed, or it should be "viewed in its totality just as it is" (i.e. it is alright to grasp a phenomenon simply as a phenomenon). Needless to say, this represents a denial of historical materialism and a refuge in Kantian agnosticism and reveals the degree of the JCP's theoretical decay. This self-proclaimed party of "scientific socialism" is now clearly traveling on a road leading to its own "self-destruction".



Zenkokushakensha
Zip:179-0074, 1-11-12-409 Kasuga-chou Nerima-ku Tokyo Japan
tel/fax +81-3(6795)2822

E-mail to WPLL
TOP