The Stalinist System
(The Internal "Evolition" Towards "Liberalization")
Written by Hiroyoshi Hayashi (1972)
Translated by Roy West
Contents
- The Laws of Commodity Exchange and Socialism
- The Relations of Production Under the Stalinist System
- The "Socialist" Planned Economy and the Category of Capital
- Economic Reforms and the Bourgeois gEvolutionh of the Stalinist System
- The gOverallh Development of Commodity Production and the gShift to
Communismh
- Criticism of eSocialistf Economics
D. Economic Reforms and the Bourgeois gEvolutionh
of the Stalinist System
The Content of Economic Reform
The new economic system, which began to be implemented in September 1956,
is generally been referred to as gliberalizationh. This gliberalizationh
took place over a period of roughly ten years beginning from the time of
Stalinfs death, and was one inevitable outcome of the debates on value,
price and profit. However, its significance is not limited to this. More
than gliberalizationh being an outcome of these debates, the debates
themselves are an expression of the gevolutionh of the Soviet economic
system.
Already at the time of Stalinfs death, several reforms were carried out,
including the adoption of a decentralized management mechanism, a raise
in the price of agricultural products, the dissolution of MTS, expanded
autonomy for the kolhozy and state enterprises, and an increase in material incentives. Moreover,
starting from the 1962 Liberman proposals, which Khrushchev supported,
the new economic policy implemented in 1965, while developing the earlier
policies, represented a qualitative turning point. By July 1970, about
forty thousand enterprises, representing 90% of industrial production and
95% of its profits, had been transferred to the new system.
First, letfs take a quick look at the content of the new policy. The basic
idea underlying the new policy is to increase the gefficiencyh in the
management of enterprises by expanding their autonomy. This is seen, first
of all, in the remarkable decrease in the number of mandatory directives
(from 30 to 9) from upper state organs to enterprises. For the sake of
reference these are listed below.
(1) Total realized output (sales amount); (2) output of important items
expressed in quantity; (3) profit ratio as the comparative ratio between
total profit and production funds; (4) deliver to and subsidies from the
state treasury; (5) total sum of wage funds ; (6) total sum of basic state
investments; (7) fixed funds from centralized key investments and the amount
of operation starts of production facilities; (8) Development of new articles,
technological processes and the automation of mechanization of production;
(9) the amount of raw materials and machinery supplied by the upper state
organs.
Out of these nine new indications,
(1) and (3) are particularly important. Before the reforms, gtotal outputh and gcosth
were two of the thirty obligatory indexes. But the former was replaced
by (1) gtotal realized outputh, and the latter by (3) gprofit (amount and ratio)h. Now each enterprise has the right to ghoardh
(accumulate) money income for enterprise funds according to the profit
(amount and ratio) generated. The index of guse-fees for production fundsh
was also added, replacing the former gfree fundsh. Enterprises now pay
fees to the state treasury when they borrow fixed or liquid funds depending
on the size of the sum. Of the former four directives concerning workers
(number of workers, labor productivity, average wages, and the wage fund),
only the index of the wage fund remains, and even this is to be eliminated
in the near future.
The meaning of these reforms is the following. First, the fact that gtotal
outputh was replaced by gsales amounth shows that the commodities of
enterprises must now be grealizedh, i.e. sold. Production can no longer
be the only concern for each enterprise. In order to achieve the mandatory
directives, enterprises now cannot simply produce a great quantity of products,
and accumulate unsold goods. gProfith (quantity and ratio) has replaced
gcost-priceh to indicate the efficiency of production. This could be
said to be the core of the economic reforms, and characteristically reveals
the essence of the new economic policy.
The official recognition of the use of this quintessentially bourgeois
concept of gprofit ratioh to measure the gefficiencyh of capital, above
all demonstrates that the hidden capitalistic relations in the Soviet Union
are assuming an increasingly clear figure. Not accidentally, along with
the proposal to gintroduce profith, the theory of gproduction priceh
as the foundation of gprice formationh is now dominant in the Soviet
Union. Of course, gproduction priceh is a category particular to bourgeois
society, and has no relation to simple commodity production, not to mention
socialist society. But Soviet scholars, on the basis of the idea that since
gsocialismh is closer to capitalism than commodity production, argue
that gprice formationh should be based on gproduction priceh rather
than gvalueh.
What Determines the gLiberalizationh Stage of State Capitalism?
Of course, basing gprofitabilityh on invested capital rather than gcost-priceh
was a change with great practical significance for the Soviet economy.
During the time when capital was unable to display its essence as self-augmenting
value (under the Stalinist system capital was under strong state control
and management and its nature was so suppressed that it couldn't develop
freely) it was forced to accumulate contradictions inherent to this. These
contradictions emerged as a disinterest in gefficiencyh, gfrozenh capital
(the storage of raw materials, machinery and equipment), and the general
stagnation of production. Various examples can be cited to show how the
gefficiencyh of state capital has improved under the new system. For
example, in the late fifties, the excess stock of gflowingh funds had
reached 16.6 billion roubles, but under the system of gfree fundsh, enterprises
inevitably hoarded or concealed excess stock. Moreover, just prior to the
reforms of mid to late sixties, over one third of the fixed capital concentrated
by the state and then invested in gplanningh was spent just for repairs,
and roughly two million workers were engaged in repair jobs. In spite of
this, the quality of goods hardly improved!
Chart #2: Ratio of Production Increase in Agriculture
and Industry (compared to previous year)
Year
|
Industry
|
Agriculture
|
1959
|
11.4
|
0.4
|
1960
|
9.5
|
3
|
1961
|
9.1
|
3
|
1962
|
9.7
|
1
|
1963
|
8.3
|
-8
|
1964
|
7.3
|
14
|
1965
|
3.6
|
1
|
Soviet state statistics quoted in the journal Keizai hyoron [Economic Review], December 1966.Still, the economic reforms begun
in 1965 greatly changed the relationship between the state and enterprises,
putting geconomich relations at the center of gadministrativeh relations.
In this sense, the reforms abolished the system of gfree fundsh, in line
with the general objective of expanding the autonomy of the enterprises
and increasing the gefficiencyh of funds.
Prior to the reforms, the state gave funds to managers of enterprises gfree
of chargeh in order to create and expand enterprises. This can be called
the characteristic gaccumulation methodh for backward countries to invest
capital in the twentieth century. The state was naturally more concerned
with the formation of capital itself than its gefficiencyh. Before the
efficiency of national capital even enters into the equation, it must be
accumulated and actually exist.
However, once national capital is formed, the next question becomes its
gefficiencyh. In the case of Japan, this gefficiencyh was achieved
in the Meiji Period in the form of the privatization of government managed
enterprises, and in the current stage of the Soviet Union this is appearing
as gliberalizationh. The attempt to ensure the gefficiencyh of national
capital is witnessed by the effort to connect the total invested capital
to the grate of returnsh, and the conversion of the relationship between
the state and enterprises into a type of gcredit relationshiph. The latter
represents the negation of the free fund system (its direct existence as
state capital). The capital, which up to that point had been gdistributedh
by the state, is now a type of compensation loaned out (at roughly 6 percent).
Each enterprise has to pay the state a gfund use-feeh in order to obtain
fixed and liquid funds. This sort of interest on state capital is supposed
to replace the profit deductions and turnover tax as the main source of
state revenue in the future. A system of direct capital (capitalist relations)
is becoming manifest. This demonstrates that the bourgeois categories were
not merely a formal existence as had once been declared.
Of course, the apologists insist that the essence of Soviet gsocialismh
has not changed, and that the new policies only serve the functional purpose
of increasing geconomic efficiencyh. It is certain that the efficiency
of the gfundsh will be increased by the new system. Sectors of production
unable to pay the use-fee for funds and other interest will likely not
receive investment, while the most highly gefficienth sectors will absorb
more funds. This will allow the most efficient distribution of funds. But
this is nothing but the general law of capitalist society (the principle
of average profit=production price). This process cannot be justified as
gconsideration for past laborh, because this occurs under the bourgeois
form of value and capital. It is no accident or theoretical mistake that
recent Soviet scholars are claiming that the prices in the USSR should
be production prices (i.e. price in payment for average profit). This is
a decisive indication of the gmaturityh of Soviet capitalistic society.
gLiberalizationh (economic reform) signifies a developmental stage in
Soviet state capitalism, its maturity, and its turning point. The essence
and inevitability of gliberalizationh is the shift from the formation
of national capital through gprimitive accumulationh to the existence
of national capital as gcapitalh. Therefore, it is not completely unwarranted
for the Chinese Communist Party to howl about the grevivalh of capitalism
(but they one-sidedly reduce Soviet capitalism to gspeculationh, etc.)
The Stalinist system started out with the backwardness of its national
economy and the overwhelming predominance of agriculture, and achieved
the historical task of the gprimitive accumulationh of national capital
by means of exploiting the peasantry and working class through forced labor.
The task of gliberalizationh, contrarily, is to render national capital
more gefficienth. The former emphasized increases in the production of
use-value, while the latter places the emphasis on increasing the production
of value=surplus-value. The former aimed for the direct strengthening of
labor (the production of absolute surplus-value), while the goal of the
latter was to increase productive power (the production of relative surplus-value).
Labor-power thus had to be not only consumed, but exploited efficiently
(i.e. maintained and reproduced in good condition). Therefore, consumer
goods, and food, etc. had to be improved to a certain extent and increased
in quantity. The prior policy of simply exploiting agriculture thus had
to be abolished, the prices of agricultural goods raised considerably,
and the autonomy of the kolhozy expanded. This revealed the bourgeois nature of the state genterprisesh.
At this stage the ruling layers, in addition to being Stalinist bureaucrats,
were managers (enterprise directors), technicians and economists (i.e.
so-called technocrats). In a state capitalist country that has yet to reach
this historical stage, gliberalizationh is held back, and the advocates
of liberalism are suppressed as revisionists (e.g. the USSR under Stalin
or China during the Great Cultural Revolution).
Another point that merits attention is the fact that gliberalizationh
(economic reform) has led to the emergence, in a clear form, of the capital=wage-labor
relationship. In the Stalinist system, the character of state enterprises
as businesses was suppressed, and the enterprise directors existed more
as state bureaucrats than managers, and so the capital=wage-labor class
relationship did not appear in its typical form. However, under economic
reform, the emerging relationship between directors and workers is not
a comradely relationship within a gcommunityh (of course this never actually
existed), but a class relationship. Next we will look at the changes in
the wage system.
The Outcome of Economic Reform:
The Appearance of Bourgeois Class Relations
Already in the late fifties, reforms of the wage system were devised to
greatly reduce the wage ratio line and reduce the wage gaps. The shift
to a system of wage incentives was also introduced, and the progressive
piece-work system, which had accounted for 35 percent of the entire wage
system until 1956, decreased to only 0.4 percent by 1962. On the other
hand, the system of wage incentives rapidly increased from 65 to 80 percent.
The proportion of piece-work to time-scale wages also decreased from 77-23
percent in 1956 to 60-40 percent in 1962. The series of economic reforms,
initiated in 1965, led to a qualitative leap in this tendency. The new
reforms calculated the efficiency of gproduction fundsh according to
profit, and attempted to provide material incentives for the activities
of the enterprises. This measured achievement of the enterprises was linked
to the size of gwagesh. Systems of incentives had existed before, but
enterprises now actively strive for profit and receive compensation according
to profit. The amount of incentives has also increased greatly compared
to before, and represents something new (of course this is quite common
in bourgeois societies).
Chart #3: Changes in the Proportion of Incentives
Through Economic Reforms
Types of Incentives:
|
Prior to the New System (1965)
|
After the New System (1967)
|
Workersf Incentives
(Relative to wages- %)
Payment for exceeding norms:
Wage funds incentives:
Material subsidy fund incentives:
Year-end bonus:
|
@
@
16.7
15.5
0.1
-
|
@
@
18.7
17.0
3.4
4.8
|
Managers/Technicians Incentives
(Relative to fixed salary- %)
Wage funds Incentives
Material subsidy funds incentives
Year-end bonus
|
@
@
19.9
0.4
-
@ |
@
@
0.4
30.4
5.2
|
Ohara and Nagasuna (eds.), Gendai shakaishugi keizai ron
[Modern Socialist Economics] p. 243.
As is clear from chart #3, with the economic reforms, the incentives paid according to the performance
of enterprises (evaluated according to profit) in fact had class content.
Through the reforms the wage gap was expanded within each enterprise. Another
crucial point is that the salaries of managers were strongly tied to the
gperformanceh of their enterprises. Under the new system, there was no
great change in remuneration for workers, but there was a decisive change
in incentives for managers and technical staff. In other words, whereas
most of their remuneration came from the wage fund before the implementation
of the new system, this now mainly comes from the gmaterial incentive
fundh formed from an enterprisefs profit. The ratio of incentives compared
to salary also nearly doubled. The meaning of this should be perfectly
clear. The managers naturally have a great interest in raising the rate
of profit. This means that they must exploit the workers and appear as
the personification of capital. Their personal income increases in proportion
to their ability to gefficientlyh exploit the workers and increase profits.
As the personification of the functions of capital (i.e. as functional
capitalists) they must develop this nature. The fact that they do not personally
own the state enterprise funds (means of production) does not mean that
they are not capitalists, but only that they are functional capitalists.
In this sense, they now have a vital interest in increasing profit and
exploiting workers. The interests of the upper management are perfectly
clear from the table above, and here is the true class character of gliberalizationh
(economic reform).
In the Soviet Union, this once concealed or undeveloped capital= wage-labor
relationship is now clearly emerging. The commodity economy is gevolvingh,
and has turned into a capital=wage-labor class relationship. This represents
the class differentiation of the direct producers. The peoplesf or workersf
and peasantsf state has lost all substantial content, and now appears
as a bourgeois state. This indicates the level of maturity of the Stalinist
system (state capitalism), and reveals every day that this system is antagonistic
to proletariat and they must overthrown it.
|