Lenin's gOwn Wordsh(Part Four: On Economic Theory)
11. A Criticism of the Narodniks and the gEvolutionh of Capitalism
Petty Bourgeois Character of "People's Production"
gThe system of social-economic relations existing among the peasantry
(agricultural and village-community) shows us the presence of all those
contradictions which are inherent in every commodity economy and every
order of capitalism: competition, the struggle for economic independence,
the grabbing of land (purchasable and rentable), the concentration of production
in the hands of a minority, the forcing of the majority into the ranks
of the proletariat, their exploitation by a minority through the medium
of merchantfs capital and the hiring of farm laborers. There is not a
single economic phenomenon among the peasantry that does not bear this
contradictory form, one specifically peculiar to the capitalist system,
i.e., that does not express a struggle and antagonism of interests, i.e.,
that does not express advantage for some and disadvantage for others. It
is the eindustriesf in their diametrically opposite types; it is also
the case with the technical progress of farming.
gWe attach cardinal importance to this conclusion not only as regards
capitalism in Russia, but also as regards the significance of the Narodnik
doctrine in general. It is these contradictions that show us clearly and
irrefutably that the system of economic relations in the ecommunityf
village does not at all constitute a special economic form (epeoplefs
production,f etc.), but is an ordinary petty-bourgeois one.h (gThe Development
of Capitalism in Russia,h Collected Works Vol. 3 pp. 172-73)
The Narodniks were a petty bourgeois revolutionary tendency that appeared
in the Russian revolutionary movement in the latter half of the 19th century.
They aimed for the liberation of the peasants exploited under the feudal
tsarist system, while also opposing capitalism. This movement was progressive
in terms of fighting against czarism, but because of its petty bourgeois
nature, it was harshly criticized by the Marxist camp.
The fundamental idea of the Narodniks was that Russia could avoid capitalism,
and make use of the agricultural communes (the mir) to leap directly to gsocialism.h Therefore, they said that capitalist development was
not necessary in Russia, and that the appearance of the proletariat was
a ghistorical misfortune.h
The idea of gpeoplefs productionh became a pillar of Narodnik theory
(or fantasy). According to this idea, gcommunalh villages were
a unique system of economic relations, representing gpeoplefs productionh
with no relation to capitalism, that were a sort of natural society. Capitalism,
on the other hand, was seen as the root of all evil that would destroy
and upturn the idyllic agricultural relations in these communities and
introduce the gpower of money,h the source of evil, which would bring
about exploitation, oppression, and the ruin of the peasantry. The Narodniks
considered Kustarf industries (peasant handicraft industry produced for
the market) as a gpeoplefs industry,h and a truly legitimate industry,
whereas capitalistic industries were viewed as being gartificial industriesh
that were in contradiction with the gpeoplefs systemh of Russia. Moreover,
they looked at the exploitation, difficulties, and oppression of workers
within gpeoplefs productionh as resulting not from within the nascent
capitalistic relations, but rather as coming from outside, in the statefs
policies (of fostering capitalism).
Leninfs criticism was thus directed at demonstrating the petty bourgeois
nature of the Narodnik idea of gpeoplefs production.h He said that the
idea that peoplefs production was opposed to capitalism and had a non-capitalist
nature was mistaken. This is the same idea held by those (even present-day
gMarxistsh) who see an absolute opposition between monopoly-capital and
small capital. gPeoplefs productionh was petty commodity production
for the market, which already included the relationship between capital
and wage-labor, and continuously generated this relationship. This was
an initial stage of capitalism, which represented a guniversal petty bourgeois
system.h The reality of small owners having limited capital and having
to also engage in labor, and the possibility of wage workers becoming small owners themselves, was turned into the particular
theory of the communal (= wage labor) principle, and this became the basis
for the sentimental glorification of gpeoplefs production and the denial
of its capitalistic character. Their ideal was for all workers to be small
owners, which is nothing but the old, bankrupt idea of Proudhon. Ultimately
this comes down to the reactionary position of opposing capitalistic oppression
while beautifying the preceding system which contains even worse forms
of exploitation.
Contradictions of Capitalism and the Market Problems
gThe problem of realization is how to find for each part of the capitalist
product, in terms of value (constant capital, variable capital and surplus-value)
and in its material form (means of production, and articles of consumption,
specifically necessities and luxuries), that other part of the product
which replaces it on the market.h (Ibid. p. 46)
The theoretical weakness of Narodnism was concentrated in the question
of markets. For this reason, Lenin made an effort to clarify this problem.
The theoretical genealogy of the Narodniks could be traced back from Sismondi,
at the beginning of the nineteenth century, through to Robertus, and then
Rosa Luxemburg. The characteristic of this theoretical lineage is a superficial
explanation of the contradiction of crisis as resulting from an inability
to realize surplus value. It was thought natural for constant and variable capital to be realized
since they are related to production as well as consumption. But surplus
value would not be realized because it had to be consumed by capitalists,
and was too massive for this to occur. This difficulty of realization was
seen as the precise source of capitalist crisis and the difficulties for
capitalism.
They argued further that to overcome this difficulty it was necessary to
always expand foreign markets, and that since this possibility was limited
in Russia, capitalism would be stillborn and restricted.
However, the problem of the gdifficultyh of realization is not simply
a problem of the realization of surplus value. The problem is how the each
part of the product is exchanged in terms of value and material form. In
the second volume of Capital, Marx reached a solution to this problem. In fact the real problem is
the realization of constant capital. The capital of 4,000 in Department
I can be directed again to production since it stems from the means of
production. However, for the capital of 2,000 in Department II this is
not possible since this is composed of the production of materials of consumption.
It is thus necessary for an exchange to take place between the 1,000 variable
capital and 1,000 surplus value in Department I., and the 2,000 capital
in Department II.
Simple Reproduction
|
Constant Capital |
Variable Capital |
Surplus Value |
Total |
Department I
(means of production) |
4,000 |
1,000 |
1,000 |
6,000 |
Department II
(consumption materials) |
2,000 |
500 |
500 |
3,000 |
This is where the actual difficulty and basis of the problem lies, but
Narodnik scholars were not even aware of this problem. The problem is essentially the same in the case of expanded reproduction (= accumulation) as well.
The starting point here is the question of whether there is profit in the
means of production, and the need for one part of the surplus value within
the consumption materials to be turned into capital. However, this fact
does not mean that the realization of surplus is impossible, since first
of all it is possible for these parts to be exchanged. This does not indicate
the incapacity of realizing surplus value, but a contradiction inherent
to capitalism wherein the expansion of the market is mainly carried out
by means of the growth of the means of production. In other words, it indicates
gproduction for the sake of production,h or production that does not
expand consumption.
Contradictions and Progressiveness of Capitalism
gRecognition of the progressiveness of [capitalismfs] role is quite compatible
with the full recognition of the negative and dark sides of capitalism,
with the full recognition of the profound and all-round social contradictions
which are inevitably inherent in capitalism, and which reveal the historically
transient character of this economic regime. It is the Narodniks -- who
exert every effort to show that an admission of the historically progressive
nature of capitalism means an apology for capitalism -- who are at fault
in underrating (and sometimes even ignoring) the most profound contradictions
of Russian capitalism, by glossing over the differentiation of the peasantry,
the capitalist character of the evolution of our agriculture, and the rise
of a class of rural and industrial allotment-holding wage-laborers, by
glossing over the complete predominance of the lowest and worst forms of
capitalism in the celebrated ehandicraftf industries.h (Ibid. p. 596)
The Narodniks criticized Marxists for recognizing the historical necessity
and progressiveness of capitalism, calling them, for example, the gdefenders
of the power of money.h However, it was the Marxists who, more than anyone
else, strongly evaluated the tendency in the inherent tendency of capitalism
to resist control. The development of capitalism brings a wide stratum
of workers under the rule of big capital, raises the productive power of social labor, socializes labor, and brings
workers together and encourages their organization, and without these conditions
the ultimate victory of socialism would not even be posed as a question.
It is mistaken and nonsensical to reject the historical progressiveness of capitalism because of its contradictions and instability.
Such a standpoint ultimately spreads illusions and beautifies the old relations
of production. What were the old relations of production in ? This was
subjection of the peasantry to the small-scale cultivators and gregional
bloodsuckers.h This was not simply their plunder, but an affront to their personal dignity. Even if it can be said that
these old relations of subordination were only replaced by new ones, this
was still a step forward for the direct producers that brought them closer
to ultimate liberation. gCapitalism is progressive in its significance
precisely because it has destroyed the old cramped conditions of human
life that created mental stultification and prevented the producers from
taking their destinies into their own hands.h (gThe Economic Content
of Narodnism,h Collected Works Vol. 1 p. 414)
On top of this, even the instability of capitalism can be a cause of progress.
This encourages the advancement of social development (consider how an
economic crisis can act as a strong lever for the concentration of capital),
sweeping more and more people into the vortex of social life, and forcing them to reflect on the social system and think
about a system that would be truly suitable to human beings. The position
of the Narodniks of seeking to expand medieval social bonds (e.g. the community)
to society as a whole has something in common with narrow-minded trade
unionism today that clamors for the gcontainment of [economic] rationalization.h
gSismondi naturally arrived at the theory that capitalism and the capitalist employment of machines were edangerousf and urged the necessity of eretarding,f
emoderatingf and eregulatingf the growth of capitalism, and, as a consequence,
he became a reactionary. The fact that Sismondifs doctrine fails to understand
the historical role of machines as a factor of progress is one of the reasons
for the modern theory regarding it as reactionary.h (gA Characterization
of Economic Romanticism,h Collected Works Vol. 2 p. 186)
The Narodniks expressed a distrust of the factory system of large-scale
industry, and said that Marxists wanted to boil peasants in the kettle
of industry. In this passage, in response to a Narodnik scholar who defended
Sismondi saying that, gSismondi was not an enemy of machines and inventions,h
Lenin said that the problem relates to the significance of machinery in
capitalist society. To say that under capitalism the use of machinery is
gharmfulh and leads to the exploitation of workers in a new form is insufficient
and one-dimensional. From the standpoint of the ultimate liberation of
the proletariat, it is reactionary to use this as a justification to reject
the introduction of machinery. This is because, even prior to the situation
of introducing new machinery, workers are suffering under the weight of
exploitation. It is not necessarily the case that the civilized, refined
exploitation is more gharmfulh than the old, shoddy exploitation. Therefore,
the question is whether or not to recognize the significance of the role
of machinery as a gprogressive factor within this system.h It would be
reactionary for anyone to take an ambiguous standpoint regarding this point.
gThe bourgeoisie makes it its business to promote trusts, drive women
and children into the factories, subject them to corruption and suffering,
condemn them to extreme poverty. We do not edemandf such development,
we do not esupportf it. We fight it. But how do we fight? We explain
that trusts and the employment of women in industry are progressive. We
do not want a return to the handicraft system, pre-monopoly capitalism,
domestic drudgery for women. Forward through the trusts, etc., and beyond
them to socialism!h (gThe Military Programme of the Proletarian Revolution,h
Collected Works Vol. 23, p. 81)
In postwar Japanese capitalism as well, a decisive turning point was reached
with the merger of the Hachiman Ironworks and Fuji Ironworks. With the
advancing concentration of capital, even among monopoly capital ever greater
monopolies are created, the ruling power of monopoly capital is reinforced,
and the oppression of the working masses deepens through rising prices,
managed prices, and intensified management of operations. However, for
Marxists, this centralization is at the same time gprogressive,h and
an inevitable development of history. Unlike the petty bourgeoisie, Marxists
are not backward looking, and do not oppose monopoly from the utopia of
a gfairh capitalism where free competition could reign. The working class
does not supporting monopoly concentration and fight against it, but unlike
the petty bourgeoisie they have no reason to fear this. The working class
does not fight to turn monopoly capitalism back into liberal capitalism,
and holds no reformist liberal fantasies about controlling monopolies through
banning monopolies and fair trade commissions, but rather fights against
monopoly capital in order to supercede it and achieve socialism, fighting
for the future rather than the past. This is the practical conclusion that
stems from the dialectical thinking of Marxism and Leninism. This way of
thinking is completely different from the Communist and Socialist parties
who refer to themselves as gprogressiveh (kakushin), but basically represent the petty bourgeoisie. From their perspective,
Lenin would be said to be glorifying monopoly capital. The fact remains,
however, that this is how Lenin criticized the Narodniks.
Defense of Free Trade (So-Called Liberalization)
gThus, the speaker [Marx] was able to find a criterion for the solution
of the problem which at first sight seemed to lead to the hopeless dilemma
that brought Sismondi to a halt: both Free Trade and its restraint equally
lead to the ruin of the workers. The criterion is the development of the productive forces. It was immediately evident that the problem was treated from the historical
angle: instead of comparing capitalism with some abstract society as it
should be (i.e. fundamentally with a utopia), the author compared it with
the preceding stages of social economy, compared the different stages of capitalism as they
successively replaced one another, and established the fact that the productive forces of society develop
thanks to the development of capitalism. By applying scientific criticism to the arguments of the Free Traders
he was able to avoid the mistake made by the romanticists who, denying
the arguments have any importance, ethrow out the baby with the bath waterf;
he was able to pick out their sound kernel, i.e. the undoubted fact of
enormous technical progress.h (gA Characterization of Economic Romanticism,h
Collected Works Vol. 2, pp. 263-4)
Marxists do not defend or promote economic gliberalizationh -- since
this means the development and freedom of capital -- but they do recognize its progressiveness as a fact. Neither free trade nor its termination
will end the worsening position of the workers, since in either case this
is nothing but the rule of capital. However, free trade crushes the old
economic relations, or at least advances this destruction, urges the gdevelopment
of the productive power of society,h and gonly in this sense is free
trade supported by Marxists.h (Marx)
This conclusion of Marxism has particular significance today. In the latter
half of the 1960s in Japan, the liberalization of trade was sought, and
was then realized in fact. During this period, the so-called gprogressiveh
(kakushin) political parties (JCP and Socialist Party) opposed this liberalization
on the basis of the idea that it would ruin small and medium size businesses,
declining industries, and farmers, and was supposedly being forced on Japan
by the United States. Their position was basically the same level as that
of the Narodnik (= romanticists).
The outcome of liberalization was, as foreseen, the development of capitalism,
and the overseas expansion overseas of Japanese capitalism. The Marxist
proposition that the liberalization of trade means nothing but the development
of freedom for capital was completely confirmed Japanese exports that were
3 or 4 billion dollars annually around 1960 reached 12 to 13 billion dollars,
and the balance of trade that had continued to show deficits of around
2 billion dollars registered a surplus. Japanese commodities made advances,
meaning that it became the turn of monopoly capital in the steel and textile
industries to seek trade protectionism. It is clear that liberalization
was one moment in the development of the productive power of society through
the development of capitalism. Raw steel production increased from some
20 million tons at the outset to 60 million tons, with technology in this
sector leading the world, and the overseas market became increasingly important
for the steel industry. In this way, the complete bankruptcy of the one-dimensional
views of the JCP theorists -- modern-day Narodniks -- has revealed been
demonstrated by reality.
Lenin wrote, gBetter stagnation than capitalist progress -- this, essentially,
is every Naroduikfs attitude to the countrysideh (gThe Heritage We Renounceh),
and it should be clear that this view is basically the same as that of
the Socialist and Communist parties, which oppose liberalization and rationalization
from a backward-looking standpoint.
The Essence of Narodnism
gPhilosophizing about the possibility of edifferent paths for the fatherlandf
is merely the outer vestment of Narodism. But its content is representation
of the interests and viewpoint of the Russian small producer, the petty
bourgeois. That is why the Narodnik, in matters of theory, is just as much
a Janus, looking with one face to the past and the other to the future,
as in real life the small producer is, who looks with one face to the past,
wishing to strengthen his small farm without knowing or wishing to know
any thing about the general economic system and about the need to reckon
with the class that controls it -- and with the other face to the future,
adopting a hostile attitude to the capitalism that is ruining him.h (gEconomic
Content of Narodnism,h Collected Works Vol. 1 p. 503)
The sentimental romanticism of the Narodniks and their philosophy of ganother
pathh for Russia was their veil, while in fact they defended the interests
of the petty bourgeoisie. The Narodniks first, as utopian socialists, dreamt
of reaching socialism without passing through socialism. They grejectedh
capitalism -- we need to recognize that there are many different ways to
grejecth capitalism! -- and tried to obstruct the development that was
actually under way. Citing the contradictions, instability and gdangerh
of capitalism, they denied the historical progressiveness of capitalism
and declared it ginfeasible.h They opposed capitalism, but their opposition
was backward looking, and they ultimately sought human liberation through
their own romanticist fantasies rather than from within the development
of productive power through capitalism. But the Narodniks were like a two-headed
Janus. Lenin clearly exposed the reactionary characteristics of Narodnism,
but also notes that their demands for democracy in general were perfectly
justified from a historic standpoint, and Marxists should not only inherit
this view, but propose it in a more profound and correct fashion. In other
words, the Narodniks were completely reactionary as socialists, but they
had to be appreciated as revolutionary democrats.
<<Before || Lenin Index || Next>>
|